Cambridge University Press
978-0-521-86543-2 - Economy and Society in the Age of Justinian - by Peter Sarris
Excerpt



Introduction




In the year 565, in the imperial capital of Constantinople, the Emperor Justinian died, bringing to a close a reign that had lasted some forty-eight years. In death, as in life, Justinian left a deep impression on those around him. The Latin court poet Corippus declared that ‘the awesome death of the man showed by clear signs that he had conquered the world. He alone, amidst universal lamentations, seemed to rejoice in his pious countenance.’1 The memory of Justinian was to loom large in the minds of subsequent generations of emperors, just as the physical monuments built in Constantinople during his reign were long to dominate the medieval city.2 The emperor had reformed the civil law of the empire, overhauled its administrative structures, and restored imperial rule to Africa, Italy, and part of Spain; he had engaged in long drawn-out warfare with the prestige enemy of Sasanian Persia and attempted to restore peace to the increasingly fissile imperial Church. In short, through his military exertions, Justinian had done much to restore the Roman Empire to a position of military and ideological dominance in the lands bordering the central and western Mediterranean, whilst at home he had sought to bolster the legal, administrative, and religious authority of the imperial office.3

   This attempted restoration of imperial fortunes had been accompanied by a concerted effort to propagandise on behalf of the emperor and his policies. Justinian’s aides and advisers, such as the quaestor Tribonian, had sought to convey to the emperor’s subjects an image of active, triumphant, and pious rulership. In an imperial constitution of 533, for example, we find Justinian lionised as the ‘conqueror of the Alamanni, Goths, Franks, Germans, Antes, Alans, Vandals, Africans – devout, fortunate, renowned, victorious, and triumphant’.4 The constitution goes on to describe how the emperor was determined to stand victorious ‘not only over enemies in war but also over troublemakers at home, driving out their wickedness through the paths of law’.5 This was an image calculated to inspire both awe and fear. It was advertised throughout the empire through proclamations and inscriptions and was further replicated beyond the world of the court in contemporary writings that drew upon imperial propaganda, such as the Chronicle of John Malalas6 .The original version of the Chronicle records that in Constantinople, in the wake of the quelling of the ‘Nika’ insurrection of 532, there was ‘great fear and the city was quiet’; in response to imperial persecution of pederasty, there was both ‘great fear and security’.7 Likewise, the early-seventh-century Chronicon Paschale records how under Justinian ‘there arose great imperial terror’.8 Such fear was regarded by Justinian and his entourage as a vital tool of effective imperial government.9

   The official representation of Justinian’s personal rule, as expressed through the medium of the imperial edicts and constitutions promulgated during his reign, was not couched solely in terms of imperial omnipotence, however.10 Rather, particularly from Justinian’s provincial and administrative legislation, there emerges the picture of an imperial office obliged to contend with what are presented as highly powerful and deeply insidious vested interests amongst elements of the imperial bureaucracy and the governing classes of the empire. This sense is conveyed with particular clarity in an imperial edict issued in the year 538–9 concerning the fiscal, civil, and military administration of Alexandria and the provinces of Egypt.11 The contents of the 538–9 edict are highly informative, for they present a picture of the Emperor Justinian rounding angrily on his praetorian prefect, John the Cappadocian, claiming that the imperial authorities in Constantinople and Alexandria had shown themselves largely incapable of supervising the collection of taxes from Egypt – the wealthiest region of the Eastern Roman Empire. As Justinian declared:

the tax-payers insisted absolutely that everything had been exacted in its entirety, but the pagarchs and curiales and collectors of the public taxes and the various governors at the time used to so administer the business hitherto that it was impossible for anyone to become at all acquainted [with its workings] and they alone profited.12

   Justinian thus singled out for criticism a select body of imperial officials: tax-collectors; those responsible for fiscal districts; civic councillors; and provincial governors; that is to say, individuals holding imperial office, many of whom would also have belonged to the highest echelons of imperial and provincial land-owning society. It was the corruption and avarice of members of this clearly identified group that Justinian held responsible for the failure of the imperial authorities to receive the expected tax revenues from Egypt. The emperor represented himself as locked in conflict with lawless elements amongst the empire’s social and administrative elite, whose activities, Justinian declared, threatened ‘the very cohesion of Our state itself’.13 Likewise, in 536, Justinian had issued a constitution concerned with the governance of the province of Cappadocia: the temerity shown by the leading magnates of the region, whom the emperor described simply as the ‘mighty’ (δυνατοί), had, he declared, made him go red with anger.14

   This image of an imperial office beset with internal foes was, of course, no less propagandistic in intent than the rhetoric of imperial triumph. There was nothing inherently novel in the concept of the emperor as ever-watchful defender of the integrity of the Roman state and the guarantor of peace within it. Similarly, the rhetoric of imperial antipathy towards the ruses of the ‘mighty’ and, by inference, of imperial concern for the wellbeing of the ‘humble and meek’, was evidently derived from Holy Scripture, and the well-established concept of the emperor acting in emulation of God.15

   However, the sense conveyed by much of Justinian’s provincial legislation, that his reign witnessed a bitter struggle between the person of the emperor and elements within the political and social elite of the empire, would appear to have represented more than mere posturing on the part of Justinian and his advisers. For precisely the same picture is emergent from the literature written in response to Justinian’s policies both during the emperor’s reign and thereafter. As with Justinian’s edict on Egypt, this conflict is depicted as having focused in particular, although not uniquely, on questions of fiscality, that is to say, the operation of the imperial system of taxation. The sources indicate unequivocally that in senatorial circles in Constantinople there was palpable unease at the fiscal implications of Justinian’s attempted restoration of imperial fortunes. Upon his accession to the throne in 565, for example, Justinian’s successor, Justin Ⅱ, who would seem to have drawn the mainstay of his support from senatorial interests at court, famously declared that he found ‘the treasury burdened with many debts and reduced to utter exhaustion’.16 This sentiment soon found itself repeated in propaganda disseminated on behalf of the new regime, as also in the works of Greek authors of the late sixth century writing in the ‘high style’, such as Procopius’ continuator, Agathias, or the ecclesiastical historian Evagrius.17

   This late-sixth-century perspective on Justinian’s reign evidently drew upon criticisms of the emperor and his entourage that were already current during his lifetime. Thus Evagrius’ complaints against one of Justinian’s ministers, a certain Aetherius, who, he declares, ‘resorted to every degree of sycophancy, plundering the properties of the living and of the dead in the name of the Imperial Household, of which he was in charge under Justinian’, echo the sentiments expressed in the late 550s by the imperial bureaucrat, scholar, and antiquarian John Lydus.18 In his treatise On the Magistracies of the Roman State, Lydus bemoaned the brutal impact on his native city of Philadelphia of the attempts made by Justinian’s officials to collect the imperial taxes which they believed to be due. He recorded how

A certain Antiochus, already an old man by age, was reported to him as being master of a certain amount of gold. For that reason [the official] arrested him and suspended him from both hands with strong ropes until the old man, having denied it, was freed from his bonds a corpse. I was a spectator of that vile murder, for I knew Antiochus.19

   Lydus goes on to paint a salacious caricature of Justinian’s chief financial officer for most of the early part of his reign, John the Cappadocian, denouncing him both for his fiscal rapacity and his equally unrestrained sexual appetites: in both public and personal terms, the parvenu Cappadocian is described as lacking the self-restraint expected of a gentleman.2 Lydus’ treatise breaks off with the temporary deposition of John the Cappadocian in January 532, and the emperor’s replacement of him as praetorian prefect with a well-born aristocrat of conservative temperament by the name of Phocas, whose promotion Lydus eulogises as heralding the restoration of a golden age.21 This account is given added piquancy by the fact that Lydus must have known that Phocas was only to hold office for a matter of months, and that John the Cappodocian was destined to return. Any ‘golden age’ was to be short-lived.22

   Similar motifs emerge from the bitter invective against Justinian and his wife, the indomitable Empress Theodora, written by Procopius of Caesarea in his Secret History, once again probably composed during the emperor’s lifetime.23 In addition to dwelling on the subject of the empress’ cruelty and sexual excess, and the emperor’s tyrannous and over-centralising zeal, Procopius emphasises the deleterious consequences for the empire at large of Justinian’s all-consuming fiscal appetite. In one particularly vivid passage, Procopius purports to recount a dream that had come to a ‘notable’ in Constantinople, by which he probably meant a senator, prior to Justinian’s accession to the throne in 527. The future emperor was seen standing in the middle of the Bosphorus, guzzling up the waters that surrounded the city until the very sewers of the imperial capital ran dry.24 So too, we might infer, was Justinian to drain his subjects of their wealth.

   Whilst denouncing the emperor’s insatiable demand for tax revenues, Procopius returns time and again to a specific charge: the harm deliberately done to senatorial and land-owning interests by imperial policy. The emperor is criticised for refusing to remit taxes to landowners who had lost agricultural workers to the bubonic plague;25 he and his wife are accused of devising various strategies for seizing the estates of members of the land-owning elite of the provinces,26 and of using trumped-up charges to confiscate senatorial patrimonies.27 It is in response to an account of Justinian and Theodora’s attempts to seize senatorial estates in the wake of the Nika insurrection of 532 that Procopius adds that ‘it was for such reasons to me and most of us (τοῖς πολλοῖς ἡμῶν) that these two people never seemed to be human beings, but rather avenging demons of some sort’.28 This reference to the author’s ‘us’ is highly suggestive and provides crucial insight into Procopius’ aristocratic sympathies.

   In addition to sharing general themes, both John Lydus and Procopius can be seen to adopt a common stance in relation to individual policies and events. Procopius concurred with Lydus’ enthusiasm for Phocas, the praetorian prefect of 532;29 both authors are critical of the economies effected with respect to the imperial messenger system or cursus velox by John the Cappadocian; and, crucially, they are critical of this policy for an identical reason – the impact of this measure on landowners.30 It may be that John Lydus and Procopius knew one another and had exchanged opinions in private; it may be that Lydus had access to a copy of Procopius’ Secret History.31 Either way, both authors give voice to a shared sense of hostility towards Justinian’s fiscal policies, and resentment at his treatment of members of the upper echelons of Constantinopolitan and provincial landed society, those whom Procopius defined as the senators and those ‘reputed to be prosperous . . . after the members of the senate’.32

   Both the legal sources composed on behalf of Justinian by his entourage, therefore, and the literary works written at the time by authors of aristocratic sentiment or sympathy, such as Procopius and John Lydus, speak with one voice. Both types of source portray Justinian’s period of rule in terms of a protracted conflict between the emperor on the one hand and powerful, conservative elements within landed society and the imperial bureaucracy on the other. To some extent, this unison of testimony might be explicable in terms of the way in which Procopius frequently structures his critique of Justinian’s reign around the framework of the emperor’s own legislation.33 But Procopius is doing more than simply inverting imperial rhetoric. Rather, as with John Lydus, he gives us vivid, concrete, illustrative examples of the struggle between emperor and aristocrat, landowner and Crown: thus he describes the confiscation of the estate of Evangelus of Caesarea, ‘a man of no little distinction’, and Justinian’s connivance in the Church’s illicit acquisition of the property of Mammianus of Emessa, ‘a man of distinguished family and great wealth’.34 Both types of source describe an objective social reality. The imperial response to this reality was to advocate autocratic centralisation. Procopius’ response was to hint at opportunities for imperial assassination.35 Either way, conflict and struggle were central to the politics of the age.

   It is striking how little this perspective on Justinian’s reign has informed modern studies of the period. Historians have been happy to follow in the footsteps of Procopius, and indeed, Justinian’s own propaganda, in terms of emphasising the emperor’s military feats, his building activity, and his centralising tendencies, but they have been rather less inclined to follow the indications given by both Procopius and the imperial legislation as to this broader context to many of Justinian’s policies and the political history of his reign.36 Both the literary works and the legal texts appear to point to an important social and economic dimension to Justinian’s reform programme arising out of a bitter struggle between the imperial authorities and aristocratic interests over access to the wealth created by – and extractable from – the labouring population of the empire. Yet such indications have been largely ignored in the recent historiography.37

   That historians have tended to shy away from approaching the reign of Justinian in such terms is perhaps readily explicable. In recent decades the study of the late antique Eastern Empire has become ever more popular. Yet most of the research undertaken has tended to be essentially cultural in focus.38 As a result, ‘cultural determinism’ has become the order of the day.39 Although economic history has been written, primarily social and economic explanations for the empire’s pattern of development have not been fashionable, and hypotheses based upon concepts of class antagonism and social conflict even less so, redolent as they are of ‘Marxist’ associations and models.40 In addition, it can be argued that we simply do not possess the sort of evidence required to write a plausible socio-economic account of the age of Justinian. The first instinct of the social and economic historian has traditionally been to look to documentary evidence. For the late antique Eastern Empire of the sixth century, however, documentary sources are, on the whole, few and far between.41 Epigraphic data, archaeological evidence, and hagiographic texts can each provide crucial insights into various aspects of late antique social and economic realities, but in the final analysis, they are poor substitutes for documentary texts.42

   Yet to attempt to make sense of the reign of the Emperor Justinian in social and economic terms, and in particular, with an eye to conflict between the imperial authorities and members of the land-owning elite of the empire, would not be to impose upon the early Byzantine world an inappropriate and alien form of analysis derived from what some might regard as an outdated and discredited politico-historical ideology. Rather, as already seen, it would be to adopt the perspective of the sources themselves. The imperial legislation, the writings of Procopius, and those of John Lydus all point in the same direction. They invite a response. In order to formulate such a response, the historian has little choice but to attempt to make maximum use of such sources as are available, however limited or imperfect they may be. The chapters that follow represent an (initial) effort at just that – an attempt to build up a social and economic context in which to situate Justinian’s reign, and also to consider the implications of the empire’s pattern of social and economic development under Justinian for its subsequent post-Justinianic history.

   In so doing, great emphasis will be placed on the one region of the late antique east from which there survives a substantial body of documentary sources, namely Egypt, for which we possess valuable collections of documentary papyri. Whilst interpretation of the Egyptian material is by no means straightforward, any attempt to come to terms with the political developments of the sixth century in their social and economic setting inevitably leads back to the testimony of the papyrological sources. On one level, this is because it is only through examination of the Egyptian papyri that we may establish a firm conceptual basis from which to proceed to the study of the legal, numismatic, epigraphic, hagiographic, and archaeological evidence for the empire at large. To put things another way, it is primarily through the testimony of the papyri that we encounter the material structures and the social, administrative, and legal vocabularies preserved in the other sources, deployed, given meaning, and lived in by those who experienced them.

   The truly crucial significance of the papyri, however, lies in the fact that they preserve details of the structure, administration, and activities of a number of aristocratically owned great estates dating from the fifth, sixth, and seventh centuries. As a result, the Egyptian papyri reveal what relations between the imperial authorities, aristocratic landowners, and provincial society beyond the great estates looked like on the ground. As will be seen in chapter eight, the social, economic, and juridical character of these estates has been hotly and, at times, fiercely debated over the years. They have been variously characterised as socially preponderant proto-feudal ‘baronies’;43 relatively marginal bit-players in a provincial world dominated by autonomous peasant producers;44 and, in more recent years, ‘semi-public’ institutions which shouldered many of the administrative burdens of the late Roman state.45 Some have regarded them as highly commercialised enterprises, others as rather more primitive, essentially autarkic regimes.46 In the chapters that follow each one of these propositions will be examined, challenged, and – to varying degrees – modified. In any case, it is with Egypt that we must begin.










CHAPTER 1
Egypt and the political economy of empire




EGYPT WITHIN EMPIRE

The centrality of Egypt to the wider political economy of the Eastern Roman Empire in the early sixth century cannot be overstated.1 On one level, the significance of the region can be gauged in straightforwardly demographic terms. The cultural and administrative focal point of Egypt in late antiquity was the city of Alexandria, which, with Constantinople and Antioch, was one of the great metropoleis of the eastern Mediterranean, with a population of perhaps some 200,000–300,000.2 The lands of the Nile Valley beyond Alexandria may have supported a further five million souls, up to one third of whom, it has been estimated, may have lived in urban centres, a density of population which was not to be seen again in the Mediterranean world until the early modern period.3 While such figures can never be anything more than rough estimates, to suggest that perhaps one-quarter of the inhabitants of the Eastern Empire in about 500 lived in Egypt would not be wildly misleading.4

   The demographic contribution of Egypt to the Eastern Roman Empire was as nothing, however, in comparison to its economic significance. Egypt was the economic powerhouse of the late antique Mediterranean.5 On a recent analysis, it has been postulated that the ‘gross provincial product’ of sixth-century Egypt amounted to a minimum of some 20 million solidi.6 For the same period, it has been estimated that the region contributed three-eighths of all fiscal revenues collected by the imperial authorities from the eastern provinces.7





© Cambridge University Press